Τετάρτη 31 Αυγούστου 2011
How to Restructure Greek Debt Lee C. Buchheit G. Mitu Gulati
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1603304
Draft
5/7/10
How to Restructure Greek Debt
Lee C. Buchheit
G. Mitu Gulati
Abstract
Plan A for addressing the Greek debt crisis has taken the form
of a €110 billion financial support package for Greece announced by the
European Union and the International Monetary Fund on May 2, 2010. A
significant part of that €110 billion, if and when it is disbursed, will be used to
repay maturing Greek debt obligations, in full and on time. The success of
Plan A is not inevitable; among other things, it will require the Greeks to
accept -- and to stick to -- a harsh fiscal adjustment program for several
years.
If Plan A does not prosper, what are the alternatives? And how
quickly could a Plan B be mobilized and executed?
This paper outlines the elements of one possible Plan B, a
restructuring of Greece’s roughly €300 billion of government debt. Prior
sovereign debt restructurings provide considerable guidance for how such a
restructuring might be shaped. But several key features of the Greek debt
stock could make this operation significantly different from any previous
sovereign debt workouts.
To be sure, a restructuring of Greek debt will not relieve the
country from the painful prospect of significant fiscal adjustment, nor will it
displace the need for financial support from the official sector. But it may
change how some of those funds are spent (for example, backstopping the
domestic banking system as opposed to paying off maturing debt in full).
This paper does not speculate about whether a restructuring of
Greek debt will in fact become necessary or politically feasible. It focuses
only on the how, not the whether or the when, of such a debt restructuring.
* * * *
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1603304
Draft
5/7/10
How to Restructure Greek Debt
Lee C. Buchheit*
G. Mitu Gulati**
This paper offers no opinion on whether Greece’s debt should
be restructured and, if so, when or on what financial terms. Nor does it
speculate on what consequences, intended or unintended, might flow from
such a restructuring. We will limit ourselves solely to the issue of how such a
restructuring might efficiently be undertaken -- drawing on the lessons of past
sovereign debt restructurings (successful and otherwise) -- if a decision is
made to proceed with a debt restructuring at some point in the future.
Financial Aspects of the Debt Stock
Greece’s total debt as of end-April 2010 was approximately
€319 billion. Of that figure, the vast majority -- approximately €294 billion --
was in the form of bonds, with another €8.6 issued as Treasury bills.
Virtually all of this debt stock was denominated in Euros. Small
amounts (in aggregate, less than 2% of the total) are outstanding in U.S.
dollars, Japanese yen and Swiss francs.
Information about the holders of Greek bonds is anecdotal.
From press reports, however, it appears that French and German banks
have the heaviest exposures,1 but mutual funds, pension funds, hedge funds
and other categories of investors also own Greek bonds. Significantly, the
extent of retail (non-institutional) ownership appears to be small.
* Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton, LLP
** Duke University Law School
1 James Wilson et al., “Worries persist on exposure to Greece,” Fin. Times, April 30, 2010.
2
A significant amount of Greek bonds have been discounted by
European commercial banks with the European Central Bank (“ECB”). On
May 3, 2010, the ECB announced that those bonds would continue to be
eligible for discounting, notwithstanding the downgrading of Greek bonds
below investment grade that occurred the prior week.2
Legal Aspects of the Debt Stock
Governing law. From the legal standpoint, the salient feature of
Greece’s bond debt is that approximately 90% of the total is governed by
Greek law. Only about €25 billion of the bond debt was issued under the law
of another jurisdiction, and most of that under English law.
Collective action clauses. It does not appear from our survey
of Greek bond documentation that the instruments issued under local law
contain provisions permitting the holders to amend the terms of the bonds
after issuance (other than to correct obvious errors or technical matters).
Prior to 2004, Greek bonds issued under English law contained collective
action clauses (“CACs”) that appear3 to permit holders of 66 percent of an
issue to modify payment terms in a manner that would bind all other holders.
After 2004, Greece altered this clause in its English law bonds.4 This new
version of the CAC permits amendments to payment terms of a bond, as well
as certain other key features of the instrument, with the consent of holders of
75% or more of an issue.
Negative Pledge. Greece does not appear to have included a
negative pledge clause in its bonds issued under local law.
2 See Press Release, ECB Announces Change in Eligibility of Debt Instruments Issued or
Guaranteed by the Greek Government (May 3, 2010) available at
http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/date/2010/html/pr100503.en.html).
3 We say “appear” because the descriptions of the modification clauses in the Offering
Circulars for these bonds routinely conflate the notion of a quorum (that is, the number of
bonds required to activate a meeting of bondholders) with the percentage of bonds required
to approve an Extraordinary Resolution.
4 In 2002, a working group of the G-10 issued a report recommending reform of the standard
sovereign debt contract. See Report of the G-10 Working Group on Contractual Clauses
(September 2002) (available at http://www.bis.org/publ/gten08.htm). The Report contained
a recommended version of a collective action clause for sovereign bonds as well as other
model clauses. The new Greek CAC derives from this source.
3
The foreign law Greek bonds we have examined do contain a
negative pledge clause, but in a very unusual form. This clause requires
Greece equally and ratably to secure each of these bond issues if ever it
creates or permits to subsist any form of security interest over its revenues,
properties or assets to secure any “External Indebtedness.”
In the case of a typical emerging market sovereign bond,
external indebtedness is defined to cover borrowings denominated in a
currency other than the currency of the issuing State. And so it was with
Greek bonds issued prior to January 1, 2000 when the Euro was adopted as
the common currency of the European Union. After that date, however, the
Euro became the “lawful currency” of Greece. But Greece’s form of negative
pledge clause did not change for more than four years after the adoption of
the Euro5; the “lawful currency” just quietly ceased being the Drachma and
became instead the Euro. In practical terms, this means that Greece’s
negative pledge clause in its foreign law bonds issued prior to 2004 would
only be triggered by the creation of a lien to secure a non Euro-denominated
Greek debt.
Events of Default. Most of the Greek bonds we have examined
incorporate a standard set of Events of Default (variations can be found in a
few bonds). These include:
• failure to pay interest (with a 30-day grace period);
• other covenant defaults (with a 30-day grace period after
written notice to the issuer);
• “External Indebtedness” (above a de minimis threshold) is
accelerated, or a payment is missed under such External
5 Starting in 2004, the definition of “External Indebtedness” in Greece’s foreign law-governed
bonds changed. Under the new version of the definition, indebtedness for borrowed money
is “External” if either (i) it is denominated in a currency other than Euros or (ii) borrowed from
foreigners under a foreign law-governed contract. This change in Greece’s standard bond
documentation occurred at roughly the same time as the country began using a CAC
modeled on the G-10 recommended clause, and adopted a 25% voting threshold for
acceleration (also recommended by the G-10).
4
Indebtedness and continues beyond the specified grace
period;6
• a general moratorium is declared on “External
Indebtedness”; and
• any government order or decree prevents Greece from
performing its obligations under the bonds.
The important point to note here is that the cross-acceleration,
cross-default and moratorium event of default clauses in these bonds apply
only to External Indebtedness; a term that in Greek bonds issued prior to
2004 excludes Euro-denominated obligations. Thus, these Events of Default
in pre-2004 bonds could only be triggered by an event affecting the small
amount of Greek debt that is denominated in currencies other than Euros.
Stated differently, a payment default on a Greek Euro-denominated bond, or
the acceleration of such an instrument, would not have cross-default
consequences across much of the debt stock.7
Bondholder remedies. Prior to 2004 (when Greece adopted a
new form of CAC), individual bondholders could accelerate their bonds
following the occurrence of an Event of Default. Bonds issued after that time
incorporate a requirement that holders of 25% of the bonds vote in favor of
an acceleration -- one of the provisions recommended by the G-10 Working
Group on Contractual Clauses in 2002. (Individual rights of acceleration are
now rarely found in emerging market sovereign bonds.)
Greece in a Restructuring Context
Greece would enjoy some distinct advantages in the
restructuring of its debt, as well as a few disadvantages, in comparison with
other countries that have been forced to undergo the process.
Advantages
• Greece’s debt is overwhelming in the form of bonds, a
characteristic shared by countries like Argentina (2001-05),
6 These cross-acceleration and cross-default clauses appear in some, but not all, of
Greece’s bonds issued under local law.
7 In Greek bonds issued after 2004, these Events of Default would be triggered by an event
affecting Republic debt that was either non Euro-denominated or borrowed from foreigners
under a foreign-law governed agreement.
5
Ecuador (2000) and Uruguay (2003). Greece will therefore
be able to avoid the complexities and intercreditor rivalries
that can be occasioned by a diverse creditor universe. Iraq
(2005-08), for example, faced a commercial creditor class
composed of banks, suppliers, construction companies,
various kinds of trade creditors and even individuals. In the
end, Iraq had to settle more than 13,000 individual claims
dating back to the Saddam era.
• Greece’s debt records are fresh and up to date. When
sovereign debts have been in default for prolonged periods
before they are restructured (for example, Liberia (2009) --
more than 25 years in arrears; Iraq (2005-08) -- more than
15 years in arrears), the task is much harder.
• Greece enjoys considerable financial support from
multilateral and bilateral sources. This opens up the
possibility of being able to “credit enhance” any new Greek
debt instrument that might be issued as part of a debt
restructuring. Greece is therefore in a position similar to the
countries that issued collateralized Brady Bonds starting in
1990.
• Related to the last point, the odd nature of Greece’s
negative pledge clauses noted above (the clauses in bonds
issued prior to 2004 would not be triggered by the creation
of liens to secure future Euro-denominated indebtedness of
Greece) means that some form of collateralized Brady Bond
approach might be legally feasible for Greece without
having to obtain waivers of negative pledge restrictions in
foreign law-governed instruments issued prior to 2004.
• The fact that so few Greek bonds seem to have fallen into
the hands of retail (non-institutional) investors may also be
a blessing. Those countries (for example, Argentina (2001-
05)), that have had to deal with thousands of retail
bondholders in a debt restructuring have found this a messy
and thankless task.
• By far, however, the greatest advantage that Greece would
enjoy in a restructuring of its debt derives from the fact that
so much of the debt stock is expressly governed by Greek
law (90% or more, if our figures are correct). This raises the
6
possibility, discussed in more detail below, that the
restructuring could be facilitated in some way by a change
to Greek law.
Several other countries have restructured local lawgoverned
debts. Russia restructured Russian law-governed
instruments known as GKOs and OFZs in 1998 in parallel
with the restructuring of its English law commercial bank
debt. Uruguay restructured its local law bonds (on the
same terms as its foreign law bonds) in 2003. In each of
these prior cases, however, the local law bonds were also
denominated in local currency and formed only part of the
overall stock of the debt being restructured. While the Euro
is certainly now the local currency of Greece, it is a good
deal more besides that.
No other debtor country in modern history has been in a
position significantly to affect the outcome of a sovereign
debt restructuring by changing some feature of the law by
which the vast majority of the instruments are governed.
Disadvantages
Several features of the Greek situation may complicate any
restructuring of its debt.
• A significant percentage (perhaps more than 30 percent) of
the bonds are believed to be owned by Greek institutional
holders. A restructuring that dramatically impairs the value
of that paper could therefore place further strains on the
Greek domestic financial sector. Jamaica, which
restructured its local currency debt earlier this year, had to
walk very gingerly in designing its transaction because so
much (perhaps as much as 75%) of the affected paper was
held by Jamaican financial institutions.
• European banks are the largest holders of Greek bonds.
The stability of those institutions will be therefore very much
on the minds of Greece’s multilateral and bilateral
supporters should a debt restructuring prove unavoidable.
The sovereign debts that triggered the global debt crisis of
the 1980s were nearly all owed to international commercial
7
banks. When the debt crisis broke in 1982, the official
sector overseers of the restructuring process therefore had
to keep one eye on the debtor countries and the other on
the stability of the banking systems in the industrialized
creditor countries. It remained an uncomfortable position
for nearly seven years until the banks had time to build up
the loan loss reserves that permitted them to accept losses
in Brady Bond exchanges without alarming regulators,
stockholders or their own creditors.
In contrast, sovereign debt crises of the last 10 years or so
have affected mostly non-bank creditors -- hedge funds,
pension funds, other institutional holders of emerging
market sovereign debt, sometimes even individuals. Those
crises did not threaten the stability of the banking sectors in
creditor countries.
A restructuring of Greek debt will, in this respect, rekindle
fretful memories of the global debt crisis of the 1980s in the
minds of official sector observers.
• Greece’s debt is denominated in Euros, a currency shared
by other members of the European Union. When a Mexico
or a Philippines restructured debts denominated in U.S.
dollars in the 1980s, no one -- for that reason alone -- lost
confidence in the U.S. dollar. This same assurance cannot
be given about the restructuring of Euro-denominated debts
owed by an EU Member State.
How Might It Be Done?
Which brings us to the main event. If one were to attempt to
glean the lessons of the 50 or 60 sovereign debt restructurings of the modern
era, what would they teach about how a Greek debt restructuring should be
managed in order to achieve a prompt, orderly and fair outcome? There is
one lesson from this history that is inescapable. A sovereign debt crisis can
be a painful experience for both the debtor and its creditors; a mismanaged
sovereign debt crisis can be a catastrophically painful experience.
Transaction structure. The most likely structure for such a
transaction would be an exchange offer -- new bonds of the Hellenic
Republic would be offered in exchange for the Republic’s existing bonds.
The terms of the new bonds would determine the nature and extent of the
8
debt relief that the transaction would provide to Greece. Exchange offers
have been the norm for sovereign debt restructurings of middle income
countries since the first Brady Bond transactions in 1990.
Eligible debt. The debt eligible to participate in such an
exchange would presumably be all outstanding Greek bonds, excluding
perhaps the Treasury bills. Short-term Treasury bills have been excluded
from a number of recent sovereign debt restructurings in order to keep that
market sweet for the government’s emergency financing needs.
An interesting question will be whether some way can be found
to exclude from the restructuring the bonds in retail hands, or at least to
moderate the terms of any restructuring of those bonds. This will depend on
two things. First, the total amount of bonds in the hands of natural persons
would have to be relatively small. Institutional holders may recognize the
public relations benefit of not having widows and orphans complaining on the
evening news, but only up to a point. If the exclusion of retail holders
appreciably increases the severity of the financial sacrifice that must be
borne by institutional creditors, these sympathies will quickly fade. Second,
some mechanism must be found that will permit the government to identify
which bonds are in retail hands when the restructuring is announced.
Otherwise, bonds will tend to migrate temporarily into the hands of
individuals until the restructuring storm passes over.
New instruments. The terms of the new instrument or
instruments that would be offered in such an exchange will be a function of
the nature and extent of the debt relief the transaction is designed to
achieve. At the soft end of the spectrum would be a simple “reprofiling” of
existing bonds (or some discrete portion of them such as bonds maturing
over the next three to five years) involving a deferral of the maturity date of
each affected bond. Uruguay (2003) stretched out the maturity date of each
of its bonds by five years, while leaving the coupons untouched.
At the sharper end of the spectrum would be a transaction
designed to achieve a significant net present value (“NPV”) reduction in the
stock of debt. If Brady Bonds were chosen as the model for the transaction,
this might entail allowing holders to elect to exchange their existing credits
for either a Par Bond (a new bond exchanged at par for existing instruments,
having a long maturity and a low coupon), or a Discount Bond (a new bond
exchanged for existing instruments at a discount from the face amount of
those instruments, but typically carrying a higher coupon and perhaps a
shorter maturity than the Par Bond). The precise financial terms of the Par
9
Bond and the Discount Bond would be calibrated to achieve an equivalent
NPV reduction.
CACs. Some version of a collective action clause appears in
most of Greece’s foreign law-governed bonds. There is no reason not to use
these clauses to minimize the number of non-participating creditors.
It would work as follows: each tender of an existing bond
containing a CAC would contain a power of attorney from the owner of that
bond in favor of the government (or its exchange agent) to vote that bond at
a bondholders’ meeting (or in a written action by bondholders) in favor of a
resolution that, if approved by the requisite supermajority of holders of that
instrument, would either cause the totality of that bond to be tendered in the
exchange or cause the payment terms of the bond to be amended so as to
match the terms of one of the new instruments being offered in the
exchange. Such a resolution, if approved by the requisite supermajority of
holders (66% or 75% in Greek bonds governed by English law) would
automatically bind all holders.
Creditor consultations. As part of the restructuring process,
Greece would have to consult with significant holders of its paper, or with
committees or other ad hoc groups representing those holders. Such
consultations would be necessary to garner widespread support for the
restructuring. In addition, the IMF’s so-called “Lending Into Arrears” policy
requires a member country facing a debt restructuring to make “a good faith
effort to reach a collaborative agreement with its creditors”.
Credit enhancement. If Greece’s multilateral and bilateral
supporters were prepared to allow some portion of their emergency financing
to be used for this purpose, Greece might be able to enhance to
attractiveness of the new bonds it would offer in the exchange. In the typical
Brady Bond context, for example, the issuing countries borrowed money
from the IMF and the World Bank and used those funds to purchase U.S.
Government zero coupon obligations that were then pledged to secure the
principal payment due on the Brady Bonds at maturity. In many cases, a
pool of cash equal to 12-24 months of interest accruals on the Brady Bonds
was also set aside and pledged as partial security for the interest due on the
Brady Bonds. So the Brady Bonds represented U.S. Government risk for
principal due at maturity, and issuing country risk for interest during the life of
the Bond (apart from any amount pledged as rolling interest collateral).
The negative pledge clauses in the debt instruments of the
Brady countries did not pose an insuperable obstacle to these collateralized
10
transactions. The commercial bank creditors waived the application of the
negative pledge restrictions in their agreements, as did the World Bank and
other multilateral development banks. In the small number of cases where a
Brady country also had outstanding international bonds, arrangements were
put in place to post “equal and ratable security”.
For the reasons noted above, Greece’s negative pledge
clauses contained in bonds issued prior to 2004 would not protect holders of
those bonds in the event that Greece were to collateralize a future Eurodenominated
issue of securities. In the case of existing bonds with negative
pledge clauses that would be triggered by the issuance of a new
collateralized security, Greece would presumably seek a waiver of the
negative pledge restrictions when it invited tenders of those issues in the
exchange offer. Failing receipt of such a waiver, Greece would be obliged to
post “equal and ratable” collateral for that issue of bonds.
Credit enhancement need not take the form of collateral
security. Indeed, over time, the market grew less fond of Brady Bonds and
most countries have retired their Brady Bonds early. Obtaining a partial
guarantee of the new instruments from a creditworthy party is another option.
(The Seychelles obtained a partial guarantee from the African Development
Bank of the new debt instrument issued by the Seychelles in connection with
its debt restructuring earlier this year.) Another alternative would be to offer
holders of the new instruments a continuing “put” of those instruments to a
creditworthy party, presumably at some discount from face value. This
would allow an institutional holder of the paper to ensure that the instrument
will always have a minimum floor value, no matter what happens to the
trading price in the secondary market.
The Tactical Implications of Local Law Bonds
International investors are often leery of buying debt securities
of emerging market sovereign issuers that are governed by the law of the
issuing state. Why? Because investors fear that the sovereign might
someday be tempted to change its own law in a way that would impair the
value or the enforceability of those securities. Such changes in local law
would normally be respected by American and English courts if the debt
instruments are expressly -- or otherwise found to be -- governed by that
local law.
International capital market borrowings by industrialized
countries sometimes follow a different model. Many of these countries have
found that foreign investors are prepared to purchase local law-governed
11
debt securities of the sovereign. These investment decisions are
presumably based on a belief that industrialized countries are less likely than
some of their emerging market brethren to risk eroding future investor
confidence by opportunistically changing their own law in order to reduce
government debt service burdens.
No country in Greece’s position would lightly consider a change
of local law as an easy method of dealing with a sovereign debt crisis. The
following factors, among others, counsel extreme caution before embarking
on such a remedy.
• If done once, future investors will fear that it could be
done again. The debtor country may therefore be
compelled in future borrowings (in which international
investor participation is sought) to specify a foreign law
as the governing law of its debt instruments.
• A dramatic change in local law by one country might
allow a worm of doubt to slip into the heads of capital
market investors in other similarly-situated countries,
driving up borrowing costs around the board.
• The official sector supporters of the debtor country will
presumably balk at any action of this kind that could
unleash the forces of contagion and instability upon
other countries whose debt stocks also contain
predominantly local law-governed instruments.
• The more dramatic or confiscatory the effect of the
change of law, the higher the likelihood that it would be
subject to a successful legal challenge. More on this
below.
One legislative measure that might be perceived as balanced
and proportional in these circumstances, however, would be to enact what
amounts to a statutory collective action clause. It could operate in this way:
local law would be changed to say that if the overall exchange offer is
supported by a supermajority of affected debtholders (say, 75%, to use the
conventional CAC threshold), then the terms of any untendered local law
bonds would automatically be amended so that their payment terms (maturity
profile and interest rate) match those of one of the new instruments being
issued in the exchange.
12
Such a law, let’s call it a “Mopping-Up Law”, would thus operate
in the manner of a contractual collective action clause in a syndicated debt
instrument. Once the supermajority of creditors is persuaded to support an
amendment to the payment terms of the instrument, their decision
automatically binds any dissident minority.
Viewed another way, the Mopping-Up Law would merely
replicate at the level of the sovereign borrower the same protection enjoyed
by corporate borrowers in many countries, including Greece. For example,
we understand that in corporate reorganization proceedings under Greek
bankruptcy law, if a plan of reorganization is accepted by two thirds of the
affected creditors (including at least 40 percent of “privileged claims” such as
secured or senior claims), it will -- with court approval -- bind all creditors. A
Mopping-Up Law would achieve a similar result but at the level of a
sovereign borrower in need of a debt reorganization.
Facilitating a sovereign debt restructuring through some form of
Mopping-Up Law would be consistent with the fundamental principle that a
sovereign debtor bears the burden of persuading its creditors that a debt
restructuring is essential, that the terms of the restructuring are proportional
to the debtor’s needs, and that the sovereign is implementing economic
policies designed to restore financial health. The only question is whether
the sovereign must persuade every last debtholder of these elements, or just
a specified supermajority of affected creditors. The trend in recent years, as
evidenced by the rapidity with which CACs have been introduced into New
York-law sovereign bonds, is in favor of the supermajority threshold.
Even the relatively mild step of facilitating a debt restructuring
through the passage of a Mopping-Up Law of some kind, however, could
draw a legal challenge. In the case of Greece, such a challenge could come
from three possible sources. The first is Article 17 of the Greek Constitution.
That Article declares that no one shall be deprived of property “except for
public benefit” and conditional upon payment of full compensation
corresponding to the value of the expropriated property. The question, it
seems to us (non-Greek lawyers that we are), is whether a mandatory
alteration of the payment terms of a local law Greek bond in the context of a
generalized debt restructuring could be said to impair the value of that bond;
an instrument that, in the absence of a successful restructuring, would have
in any event been highly impaired in value. Also of possible relevance may
be Article 106 of the Greek Constitution which gives the State broad powers
to “consolidate social peace and protect the general interest.”
13
A second source of possible legal concern might lie in the
European Convention on Human Rights and its Protocols. Article 1 of
Protocol No. 1 protects the right to the “peaceful enjoyment of possessions”.
This right may be restricted only in the public interest and only through
measures that do not impose an individual and excessive burden on the
private party. That said, Article 15 of the Convention permits measures,
otherwise inconsistent with the Convention, to deal with a “public emergency
threatening the life of the nation”.
Finally, foreign holders of local law-governed Greek bonds
subject to the Mopping-Up Law might look to Greece’s Bilateral Investment
Treaties for redress. BITs protect against expropriation without
compensation, as well as unfair and inequitable treatment. It appears that
Greece has signed more than 40 BITs with bilateral partners.
Assuming some version of a Mopping-Up Law could survive
any legal challenge, however, it could have significant tactical implications for
a Greek debt restructuring. More than 90% of Greek bonds are governed by
local law. If, to use our example, holders of 75% of all eligible bonds (local
law and foreign law) were to support a restructuring, our version of a
Mopping-Up Law should operate to ensure that more than 90% of the debt
stock will be covered by the restructuring. The Mopping-Up Law would not
affect holders of foreign law bonds. Participation by those holders would
need to be encouraged by moral suasion and the use of contractual
collective action clauses in the relevant bonds.
How Long Would a Restructuring Take?
Our guess? If done efficiently, five to six months, less if
necessary.
One month or so would be needed for preparation; one to two
months for creditor consultations; one month during which the exchange
offer would be in the market and road shows would take place; another four
to six weeks to convene bondholder meetings for those bonds containing
CACs, and two to four weeks to prepare for a closing.
If done efficiently.
* * * *
GREEK DEBT -- THE ENDGAME SCENARIOS Lee C. Buchheit Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP - New York Office G. Mitu Gulati
NEWYORK:2376914.1
GREEK DEBT -- THE ENDGAME SCENARIOS
Lee C. Buchheit
Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP - New York Office
G. Mitu Gulati
Duke University - School of Law
April 18, 2011
Abstract:
Perhaps Greece -- a country with a debt to GDP already approaching 150
percent and set to move even higher -- avoids a debt restructuring. Perhaps
not.
What are the possible scenarios if Greece cannot return to the capital
markets to refinance this gargantuan debt stock once its EU/IMF bailout
package expires in two years time? What would a Greek debt restructuring
look like after mid-2013? And (sharp intake of breath here) what would
happen if such a debt restructuring were undertaken before that point?
Draft
4/18/11
GREEK DEBT --THE ENDGAME SCENARIOS
Lee C. Buchheit & Mitu Gulati1
At about this time last year, we wrote a short paper entitled “How to
Restructure Greek Debt.”2 The intervening months have seen the following
major events in the Eurozone debt crisis:
In May 2010, Greece concluded an agreement with the
Eurozone member states, with the backing of the IMF, for
access to a €110 billion facility (€80 billion from the Eurozone
and €30 billion from the IMF).3 That amount was judged to
be sufficient to allow Greece to repay -- in full and on time --
all public sector debts maturing during the three-year IMF
program period and to cover anticipated budget deficits
during that period. One objective of this total bailout of
Greece was to staunch any risk of contagion to the other
European peripheral countries.
The European Central Bank promptly embarked on a
program of open market purchases of Greek and other
Eurozone periphery debt in order to “ensure an orderly
monetary policy transmission mechanism.”4 This program
continues, in fits and starts, as of this writing. The ECB is
thought now to own €40-50 billion of Greek sovereign bonds
purchased in the secondary market.
1 Partner, Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLP (New York) and Professor, Duke Law School,
respectively.
2 Available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1603304. The published
version of this paper can be found at Lee C. Buchheit & Mitu Gulati, Restructuring a Nation’s
Debt, Int’l Fin. L. Rev. 46 (June 2010). A copy is attached to this document.
3 See Ronald Janssen, Greece and the IMF: Who Exactly is Being Saved? CEPR Draft (July
2010) (available at http://www.cepr.net/documents/publications/greece-imf-2010-07.pdf).
4 See Ansgar Belke, Driven by the Markets? ECB Sovereign Bond Purchases and the Securities Market
Program, Directorate General for Internal Policies, Working Paper (June 2010) (available at
http://www.europarl.europa.eu/document/activities/cont/201006/20100610ATT75796/20100610ATT75796
EN.pdf).
2
On October 18, 2010, German Chancellor Angela Merkel and
French President Nicholas Sarkozy took a stroll on a beach in
Deauville, France. When they returned holding hands (in a
figurative sense, naturally), they announced plans to alter the
EU treaty to put in place a permanent “crisis management
system” that would include provisions to ensure the
“adequate participation of private creditors”.5 Unfortunately,
Mr. Sarkozy and Mrs. Merkel did not confide to the markets
precisely what this “adequate participation” entailed.
Predictably, the markets assumed the worse, resulting in a
sell-off of Eurozone periphery sovereign debt.6 Yields on that
paper moved sharply higher.
In late November 2010, Ireland asked for, and received, its
own €85 billion bailout package, also with IMF conditionality.7
To calm the markets after the Deauville adventure, the finance
ministers of the five biggest EU member states announced on
November 28, 2010 that “any private sector involvement [in
Eurozone sovereign debt restructurings] … would not be
effective before mid-2013”.8 In other words, investors were
assured -- or thought they had been assured -- that all existing
Eurozone sovereign debt instruments would be immune from a
debt restructuring.
On March 8, 2011, Greece filed a registration statement with
the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission enabling the
country to issue bonds to “diaspora” Greek investors at rates
significantly below market.9
5 See Erick Nielsen, Eurozone Bond Haircuts Must Look Appealing, Financial Times, November
9, 2010.
6 See Peter Spiegel, Anger at Germany Boils Over, Financial Times, November 16, 2010; Simon
Tilford, Eurozone Politicians are Playing with Fire, CER Insight, November 15, 2010.
7 See Ian Traynor, IMF and EU bail out Ireland amid fears of Eurozone contagion, The Guardian,
November 22, 2010.
8 Statement by the Eurogroup, available at
http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ecofin/118050.pdf
9 A Greek Diaspora Bond Odyssey, Financial times (Alphaville), March 9, 2011 (available at
http://ftalphaville.ft.com/blog/2011/03/09/509211/a-greek-diaspora-bond-odyssey/).
3
On April 6, 2011, as this paper was being written, Portugal
asked the European Union for financial assistance.10
March 23, 2011 saw the release of a term-sheet for a
permanent facility to assist distressed Eurozone sovereigns
after 2013, the European Stabilization Mechanism (“ESM”).
The term sheet makes clear that ESM loans will be given
preferred creditor status.11 A similar claim to preferred
creditor status has not been made (or at least not yet been
made) for the €80 billion EU contribution to the Greek bailout
package.
Last month, the Greek Finance Minister said publicly that
even the €110 billion EU/IMF facility might not be enough to
tide Greece over until 2013.12
To date, one or more of the following concerns about permitting a
restructuring of Eurozone sovereign debt have induced the official sector to
continue a policy of total bailouts of all afflicted countries.
Contagion. Confronted with a debt restructuring in one
country, will the markets recoil from all peripheral Eurozone
countries, perhaps sparking a general crisis?
Effect on banks. Eurozone commercial banks hold the lion’s
share of Greek sovereign bonds. A debt restructuring that
significantly reduced the balance sheet valuation of these
assets could threaten the solvency of some institutions,
perhaps requiring a recapitalization from the host
government.
Honi soit qui mal y pense. Would a Eurozone sovereign debt
restructuring indelibly stain the reputation of the Euro and
perhaps even undermine the foundations of the monetary
union itself?
10 See Peter Wise and Peter Spiegel, Portugal appeals for EU bail-out, Financial Times, April 7,
2011.
11 See The Eurozone’s ESM Permanent Bailout Fund, Financial Mirror, March 23, 2011 (available
at http://www.financialmirror.com/Columnist/Global_Markets/752).
12 Id.
4
Although each of these constraints is still present to some degree
one year after the Greek debt crisis erupted, it is no longer obvious that they,
individually or in aggregate, continue to justify complete paralysis. The markets
have had an opportunity to focus on the differences in the financial positions of
the various peripheral Eurozone countries. Putting aside the obvious fact that
the policy of total official sector bailouts has not prevented contagion (see Ireland
and Portugal), blind indiscriminate contagion has diminished as a risk. As for the
commercial bank holders, they have been given a year to sell or hedge
exposures, or otherwise provision against an eventual hit to the value of their
Greek positions. Some are no doubt still uncomfortably exposed, but this list
should be smaller than it was a year ago. (It is not clear to us whether all banks
have in fact made hay while this sun has been shining, but they have at least
been given a chance to do so.)
We have now been asked to update our earlier assessment of the
Greek debt situation in light of these developments. In particular, we have been
asked to speculate on possible endgame scenarios for the Greek debt crisis.
We divide these scenarios into three groups: (i) Greece goes the
distance with the current IMF/EU program and a debt restructuring is avoided
altogether, (ii) a debt restructuring of some kind becomes unavoidable after June
2013 when the EU’s “read my lips -- no restructuring until 2013” promise lapses
by its terms, and (iii) a liability management transaction affecting some or all of
the Greek debt stock is launched before 2013.
The Official Scenario -- Greece Goes the Distance
Under this scenario -- which enjoys the public support of Greece’s
official sector sponsors (the IMF and the EU) as well as the Greek authorities
themselves -- Greece will stick with its program of fiscal austerity for the full three
years. At the end of that period (apparently the initial prediction of renewed
market access in 2012 has now been withdrawn), Greece returns to the capital
markets to refinance its maturing debt and fund amortizations due on the EU/IMF
bailout loans. The markets, this theory contends, will be so impressed with the
turnaround in Greece’s fiscal position that private sector monies will be advanced
in sufficient quantities and at tolerable interest rates to permit Greece to resume
normal rollovers of its maturing debts. Over time, Greece will run primary budget
surpluses and will begin to nibble at its (admittedly) colossal debt stock. This,
says the official sector, is the benignant future that awaits both Greece and all of
its lenders.
5
The Risks
On its current path, the Greek public sector debt in 2013 will
represent 150-170% of GDP. Moreover, more than half of
that debt stock will by then be in the hands of official sector
creditors (the EU, the ECB and the IMF), at least one of
which (the IMF) claims for itself preferred creditor status. Will
the private capital markets really be eager to resume
financing a country in this precarious position?
Two more long years of fiscal austerity lay ahead for Greece.
Will the Greek politicians be able to hold the social/political
consensus together that long?
What happens if Greece begins to miss its IMF performance
targets? Will the IMF and EU casually relax the conditionality
so that drawdowns can continue under the €110 billion
facility, or might German parliamentarians insist on taking a
harder line? Waiving compliance with the fiscal performance
targets in order to avoid a debt default, of course, risks
sending this message to other prospective borrowers from
official sector bailout facilities: “Eurozone countries in
financial distress can expect assistance from the EU and IMF
in two -- but only two -- circumstances: (i) when those
countries adopt and stick to stern fiscal austerity programs or
(ii) when they don’t”.
The €110 billion facility was intended by its authors to be an
overwhelming demonstration of financial firepower -- a
veritable Hank Paulson bazooka. If this was the antidote to
contagion, however, it failed. Ireland has succumbed. So
has Portugal. If one of these other countries decides to
pursue a debt restructuring before 2013, might not that
precedent fuel calls for something similar in Greece?
6
Post-2013 Scenarios
We see four possible scenarios if Greece is unable to regain
market access in late 2013. Three involve a post-2013 restructuring of the Greek
debt stock, while one envisions that Greece muddles on for an indefinite period
as a ward of the official sector.
Scenario One: The Official Sector Takes the Spear. By June
2013, more than one-half of the Greek debt stock will be in the hands of official
sector lenders. By significantly restructuring their own claims against the
country, these official sector lenders could attempt to render Greece presentable
to the private markets.
The Risks
It is difficult (read, nearly inconceivable) to envision a political
environment that would permit the EU and ECB -- much less the
IMF -- to sacrifice their taxpayers’ money in order to ensure full
and timely repayment of commercial creditors, some of whom
are earning yields in excess of 12%.
Will the EU carry the burden of such a restructuring alone, or
will it expect the IMF to chip in? And if the latter, what, if
anything, will be left of the IMF’s sacrosanct “we never
restructure” status?
Scenario Two: The Private Sector Creditors Take the Spear:
Under this scenario, the holders of the remaining Greek debt stock still in private
hands in mid-2013 will be presented with a restructuring proposal that effectively
eviscerates the value of their paper.
The Risks
Even a total write-off of that remaining one-third to one-half of
the debt stock may not be enough to return Greece to
creditworthiness.
These creditors will never go gentle into the good night of a total loss
of value. Something coercive, something truly ugly, will be needed to
prod them into the abattoir. What effect would this have on future
lending to Greece or, for that matter, to other Eurozone sovereigns?
7
Scenario Three: All Together Now. The third alternative involves a
joint debt restructuring by both official and private sector lenders sometime after
the middle of 2013. With private sector involvement, the official sector can’t be
accused of mollycoddling commercial lenders; with official sector involvement,
those commercial lenders would not face a total write off of the value of their
claims.
The Risks
Some might argue that this demonstration of fraternal solidarity will
only end up alienating the affections of both groups, the official and the
private lenders. Would it not be better, they might argue, to keep one
camp sweet for future borrowings?
Unless the terms of the two restructurings were calibrated to be
equivalent in a net present value sense, this approach risks
intercreditor jealousy and suspicion.
Scenario Four: Wardship. Perhaps the paralyzing fear of a
Eurozone sovereign debt restructuring will persist even after 2013 has come and
gone. If so, Greece could be relegated to the status of a ward of the official
sector for an indefinite period. The remaining bonds in the hands of commercial
lenders, and the amortizations due on the first round of EU/IMF loans, would
presumably all be paid with the proceeds of drawings under successor official
sector credit facilities. After the passage of a few more years, virtually all of the
Greek debt stock will then be owed to its official sector rescuers.
The Risks
This could be politically unpalatable to the Greeks. Someone is bound
to say that when Greece took the first €110 bailout, this was equivalent
to a bibulous landlubber accepting the King’s schilling from the
sergeant of a Royal Navy press gang in order to buy one more round
of drinks: when the poor fellow wakes up in the morning he will be
facing ten years before the mast in His Majesty’s service.
8
It can’t be a very pleasant alternative for the official sector either.
Pre-2013 Restructuring Scenarios
If for any reason Greece cannot, or does not wish to, wait until mid-
2013 before addressing its debt stock (a decision that presumably would require
at least the passive acquiescence of the EU, the IMF and the ECB), broadly
speaking we see two possible scenarios.
The EU’s post-Deauville assurance that there will never be a
restructuring of an existing Eurozone sovereign debt instrument (at least until
2013) presents something of an obstacle to any pre-2013 restructuring of
Eurozone sovereign debt instruments. The face-saving solution may be
linguistic. A voluntary liability management transaction undertaken by the debtor
country before 2013, the argument goes, is not a “restructuring” as that term was
used in the post-Deauville assurance. Restructuring, it may be claimed,
connotes a degree of coercion on the affected creditors. But if the creditors
themselves elect voluntarily to participate in a liability management transaction to
improve the creditworthiness of their debtor, who in the official sector can or
should gainsay that decision?
Scenario One -- A Light Dusting. One possibility would be to
approach the private sector (principally northern European commercial bank)
holders of Greek bonds with a mild restructuring proposal that limits, or even
neutralizes altogether, any net present value loss they would suffer as a result of
participating in the transaction. A simple Uruguay-style13 reprofiling of the debt
stock with no haircut to principal would fit this bill. To ensure widespread creditor
acceptance, some might urge that any new instrument issued to effect the
restructuring benefit from credit enhancement (a partial guarantee from the
official sector, for example, or collateral security à la Brady bonds) so as to
neutralize the negative NPV consequences of the stretch-out of maturities. One
obvious motivation for a mild restructuring of this kind would be to cushion its
effect on the balance sheets of overexposed northern European commercial
banks. A second motivation, of course, would be to move existing debt
maturities beyond the current program period so as to liberate a portion of the
€110 billion bailout facility for other purposes.
13 In 2003, Uruguay “reprofiled” its external debt stock by extending the maturity of each of its 18
series of bonds by five years. There was no haircut to principal; coupons were kept the same.
See Lee C. Buchheit and Jeremiah S. Pam, Uruguay’s Innovations, 19 J. Int’l Banking L. and
Reg. 28 (2004).
9
The Risks
Will such a light dusting of the debt stock return Greece to a
sustainable position, or will it be just the first of a two stage
restructuring with the real blood-letting deferred to stage two?
Neutralizing the negative NPV effect of a maturity stretch out by adding
credit enhancements is expensive and contraindicated for a country
facing a severe debt crisis. But asking bondholders voluntarily to
accept an NPV loss, however, will surely test the sponsors’ powers of
persuasion.
Overexposed commercial banks that currently hold Greek sovereign
paper in their “hold to maturity” book at or near par value may want an
assurance that a transaction of this kind will not require an immediate
marking of their positions to market values.
Scenario Two: The Full Monty. For the sake of completeness, the
final option would involve a full restructuring of the Greek debt stock prior to 2013
in order to give the country a visibly sustainable debt profile as soon as possible.
Such a restructuring would presumably look to cut the size of the debt stock in
nominal terms as well as to iron out the maturity profile, all to the end of
positioning Greece to return to the capital markets within a reasonable period of
time following the closing of the transaction.
The Risks
A Full Monty approach would require all concerned to jettison any
illusions about sponsoring a wholly voluntary transaction.
This will lead to the usual discussion about how -- in the odious patois
of investment bankers -- to “incentivize” the bondholders to participate.
Change local law to compel participation (more than 90% of the debt
stock is governed by Greek law)? Threaten a payment default on any
untendered bonds (the “abandon all hope ye who do not enter here”
tactic)? Declare any non-tendered bonds ineligible at the ECB
discount window?
Having spent billions of Euros of taxpayer money to stave off any
restructuring of Eurozone sovereign debt, will the political class in
Europe really be prepared now to careen to the other extreme of
countenancing a savage debt restructuring?
10
A major tremor of this kind affecting the Greek debt would indeed be
felt in Lisbon, Madrid and elsewhere in peripheral Europe.
The Historical Perspective
We have all been here before.
In August of 1982, Mexico was forced to declare a moratorium on
the repayment of its external debt owed to commercial banks. Over the course
of the next two years, more than twenty other countries followed suit -- it later
came to be called “the global debt crisis” of the 1980s.
Then, as now, the lenders to these sovereigns were primarily
commercial banks. Then, as now, some of those banks were dangerously
overexposed and could not have endured any significant writedown of the value
of their sovereign credit portfolios. Then, as now, the banks approached the
official sector institutions asking that the official sector either lend the sovereign
borrowers the money to continue normal debt service on their bank credits or,
failing that, guarantee the banks’ loans.
Then, unlike now, the banks were rebuffed. The official sector flatly
refused to bail the banks out of their bad credit decisions in the early 1980s. But,
in recognition of the balance sheet fragility of some of those institutions, the
official sector (and in particular the U.S. Treasury Secretary) agreed to use its
influence over the sovereign debtors to promote a debt restructuring technique
that avoided any need for the banks to write down the value of their sovereign
portfolios.
This technique, later named after U.S. Treasury Secretary James
Baker, had four components.
The debtor country was required to sign up to an IMF
stabilization and adjustment program.
The principal of the banks’ loans was rescheduled over
relatively brief periods -- 18 to 24 months.
Interest payments on those rescheduled loans, however,
had to be kept current to avoid negative accounting
consequences for the banks.
11
Because many countries lacked the resources even to pay
interest, the banks were compelled to lend the debtors “new
money” which was then recycled back to the banks as
interest payments on their existing exposure.14
As the 1980s rolled sweetly on, the four elements of this Baker Plan
debt restructuring technique were repeated, sometimes four or five times, in the
afflicted debtor countries. In public, Secretary Baker and others expressed
fathomless confidence that the banks would never experience a loss on their
sovereign credits. Why? The debtor countries, it was predicted, would after
years of IMF tutelage “grow” out of their debt problems. In private, however, the
official sector players warned the commercial banks to begin provisioning their
loan loss reserves against the possibility that a loss might someday materialize.
After seven years of the Baker Plan, a new U.S. Treasury
Secretary, Nicholas Brady, announced (on March 10, 1989) a shift in U.S.
Government policy toward the management of the global debt crisis. Secretary
Brady encouraged the banks to write off a portion of their exposure to the debtor
countries, and to stretch out repayment of the balance for 30 years, as a means
of ending the global debt crisis in a single stroke. And, more or less, the Brady
Initiative did just that. Banks swallowed (modest) losses on their sovereign
portfolios; debtor countries regained (modest) market access; the banks’ loan
loss reserve provisions (built up over the prior seven years) cushioned the
balance sheet effect of the losses. A banking crisis in the developed countries
did not follow the launch of the Brady Initiative.
The debt management technique adopted by Secretary Baker and
his official sector colleagues in 1982 therefore had the effect of grabbing the
commercial bank creditors by their noses and holding them in place as the
lenders of record until a more durable solution to the problem could be
implemented. The concession made to the bank lenders at the time was a
restructuring technique that avoided accounting losses while the banks were
provisioning their loan loss reserves. When the day of reckoning eventually
arrived with Secretary Brady, the losses were felt by the bank creditors that had
made the loans in the first place.
14 See Lee C. Buchheit, Whatever Became of Old New Money, Int’l Fin. Law Review, December
1990.
12
Contrast this to the debt management technique being used in
Europe in 2010-2011. This time around, the official sector players are not
holding the original lenders by the nose; the official sector is actually buying out
the original lenders in full and on time as each existing bond matures and is paid
by drawing down an official sector credit lines. The difference is this -- if the
sword of a debt restructuring must eventually fall in order to render Greece’s debt
stock manageable (something that most economists view as inevitable), that
sword will fall principally on the neck of the official sector lenders. The original
creditors will have swapped places in the tumbrel with official lenders quite
literally in the shadow of the guillotine.
* * * *
Attachment:
Lee C. Buchheit & Mitu Gulati, How to Restructure Greek Debt (May 2010)
(available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1603304).
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1603304
Draft
5/7/10
How to Restructure Greek Debt
Lee C. Buchheit
G. Mitu Gulati
Abstract
Plan A for addressing the Greek debt crisis has taken the form
of a €110 billion financial support package for Greece announced by the
European Union and the International Monetary Fund on May 2, 2010. A
significant part of that €110 billion, if and when it is disbursed, will be used to
repay maturing Greek debt obligations, in full and on time. The success of
Plan A is not inevitable; among other things, it will require the Greeks to
accept -- and to stick to -- a harsh fiscal adjustment program for several
years.
If Plan A does not prosper, what are the alternatives? And how
quickly could a Plan B be mobilized and executed?
This paper outlines the elements of one possible Plan B, a
restructuring of Greece’s roughly €300 billion of government debt. Prior
sovereign debt restructurings provide considerable guidance for how such a
restructuring might be shaped. But several key features of the Greek debt
stock could make this operation significantly different from any previous
sovereign debt workouts.
To be sure, a restructuring of Greek debt will not relieve the
country from the painful prospect of significant fiscal adjustment, nor will it
displace the need for financial support from the official sector. But it may
change how some of those funds are spent (for example, backstopping the
domestic banking system as opposed to paying off maturing debt in full).
This paper does not speculate about whether a restructuring of
Greek debt will in fact become necessary or politically feasible. It focuses
only on the how, not the whether or the when, of such a debt restructuring.
* * * *
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1603304
Draft
5/7/10
How to Restructure Greek Debt
Lee C. Buchheit*
G. Mitu Gulati**
This paper offers no opinion on whether Greece’s debt should
be restructured and, if so, when or on what financial terms. Nor does it
speculate on what consequences, intended or unintended, might flow from
such a restructuring. We will limit ourselves solely to the issue of how such a
restructuring might efficiently be undertaken -- drawing on the lessons of past
sovereign debt restructurings (successful and otherwise) -- if a decision is
made to proceed with a debt restructuring at some point in the future.
Financial Aspects of the Debt Stock
Greece’s total debt as of end-April 2010 was approximately
€319 billion. Of that figure, the vast majority -- approximately €294 billion --
was in the form of bonds, with another €8.6 issued as Treasury bills.
Virtually all of this debt stock was denominated in Euros. Small
amounts (in aggregate, less than 2% of the total) are outstanding in U.S.
dollars, Japanese yen and Swiss francs.
Information about the holders of Greek bonds is anecdotal.
From press reports, however, it appears that French and German banks
have the heaviest exposures,1 but mutual funds, pension funds, hedge funds
and other categories of investors also own Greek bonds. Significantly, the
extent of retail (non-institutional) ownership appears to be small.
* Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton, LLP
** Duke University Law School
1 James Wilson et al., “Worries persist on exposure to Greece,” Fin. Times, April 30, 2010.
2
A significant amount of Greek bonds have been discounted by
European commercial banks with the European Central Bank (“ECB”). On
May 3, 2010, the ECB announced that those bonds would continue to be
eligible for discounting, notwithstanding the downgrading of Greek bonds
below investment grade that occurred the prior week.2
Legal Aspects of the Debt Stock
Governing law. From the legal standpoint, the salient feature of
Greece’s bond debt is that approximately 90% of the total is governed by
Greek law. Only about €25 billion of the bond debt was issued under the law
of another jurisdiction, and most of that under English law.
Collective action clauses. It does not appear from our survey
of Greek bond documentation that the instruments issued under local law
contain provisions permitting the holders to amend the terms of the bonds
after issuance (other than to correct obvious errors or technical matters).
Prior to 2004, Greek bonds issued under English law contained collective
action clauses (“CACs”) that appear3 to permit holders of 66 percent of an
issue to modify payment terms in a manner that would bind all other holders.
After 2004, Greece altered this clause in its English law bonds.4 This new
version of the CAC permits amendments to payment terms of a bond, as well
as certain other key features of the instrument, with the consent of holders of
75% or more of an issue.
Negative Pledge. Greece does not appear to have included a
negative pledge clause in its bonds issued under local law.
2 See Press Release, ECB Announces Change in Eligibility of Debt Instruments Issued or
Guaranteed by the Greek Government (May 3, 2010) available at
http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/date/2010/html/pr100503.en.html).
3 We say “appear” because the descriptions of the modification clauses in the Offering
Circulars for these bonds routinely conflate the notion of a quorum (that is, the number of
bonds required to activate a meeting of bondholders) with the percentage of bonds required
to approve an Extraordinary Resolution.
4 In 2002, a working group of the G-10 issued a report recommending reform of the standard
sovereign debt contract. See Report of the G-10 Working Group on Contractual Clauses
(September 2002) (available at http://www.bis.org/publ/gten08.htm). The Report contained
a recommended version of a collective action clause for sovereign bonds as well as other
model clauses. The new Greek CAC derives from this source.
3
The foreign law Greek bonds we have examined do contain a
negative pledge clause, but in a very unusual form. This clause requires
Greece equally and ratably to secure each of these bond issues if ever it
creates or permits to subsist any form of security interest over its revenues,
properties or assets to secure any “External Indebtedness.”
In the case of a typical emerging market sovereign bond,
external indebtedness is defined to cover borrowings denominated in a
currency other than the currency of the issuing State. And so it was with
Greek bonds issued prior to January 1, 2000 when the Euro was adopted as
the common currency of the European Union. After that date, however, the
Euro became the “lawful currency” of Greece. But Greece’s form of negative
pledge clause did not change for more than four years after the adoption of
the Euro5; the “lawful currency” just quietly ceased being the Drachma and
became instead the Euro. In practical terms, this means that Greece’s
negative pledge clause in its foreign law bonds issued prior to 2004 would
only be triggered by the creation of a lien to secure a non Euro-denominated
Greek debt.
Events of Default. Most of the Greek bonds we have examined
incorporate a standard set of Events of Default (variations can be found in a
few bonds). These include:
• failure to pay interest (with a 30-day grace period);
• other covenant defaults (with a 30-day grace period after
written notice to the issuer);
• “External Indebtedness” (above a de minimis threshold) is
accelerated, or a payment is missed under such External
5 Starting in 2004, the definition of “External Indebtedness” in Greece’s foreign law-governed
bonds changed. Under the new version of the definition, indebtedness for borrowed money
is “External” if either (i) it is denominated in a currency other than Euros or (ii) borrowed from
foreigners under a foreign law-governed contract. This change in Greece’s standard bond
documentation occurred at roughly the same time as the country began using a CAC
modeled on the G-10 recommended clause, and adopted a 25% voting threshold for
acceleration (also recommended by the G-10).
4
Indebtedness and continues beyond the specified grace
period;6
• a general moratorium is declared on “External
Indebtedness”; and
• any government order or decree prevents Greece from
performing its obligations under the bonds.
The important point to note here is that the cross-acceleration,
cross-default and moratorium event of default clauses in these bonds apply
only to External Indebtedness; a term that in Greek bonds issued prior to
2004 excludes Euro-denominated obligations. Thus, these Events of Default
in pre-2004 bonds could only be triggered by an event affecting the small
amount of Greek debt that is denominated in currencies other than Euros.
Stated differently, a payment default on a Greek Euro-denominated bond, or
the acceleration of such an instrument, would not have cross-default
consequences across much of the debt stock.7
Bondholder remedies. Prior to 2004 (when Greece adopted a
new form of CAC), individual bondholders could accelerate their bonds
following the occurrence of an Event of Default. Bonds issued after that time
incorporate a requirement that holders of 25% of the bonds vote in favor of
an acceleration -- one of the provisions recommended by the G-10 Working
Group on Contractual Clauses in 2002. (Individual rights of acceleration are
now rarely found in emerging market sovereign bonds.)
Greece in a Restructuring Context
Greece would enjoy some distinct advantages in the
restructuring of its debt, as well as a few disadvantages, in comparison with
other countries that have been forced to undergo the process.
Advantages
• Greece’s debt is overwhelming in the form of bonds, a
characteristic shared by countries like Argentina (2001-05),
6 These cross-acceleration and cross-default clauses appear in some, but not all, of
Greece’s bonds issued under local law.
7 In Greek bonds issued after 2004, these Events of Default would be triggered by an event
affecting Republic debt that was either non Euro-denominated or borrowed from foreigners
under a foreign-law governed agreement.
5
Ecuador (2000) and Uruguay (2003). Greece will therefore
be able to avoid the complexities and intercreditor rivalries
that can be occasioned by a diverse creditor universe. Iraq
(2005-08), for example, faced a commercial creditor class
composed of banks, suppliers, construction companies,
various kinds of trade creditors and even individuals. In the
end, Iraq had to settle more than 13,000 individual claims
dating back to the Saddam era.
• Greece’s debt records are fresh and up to date. When
sovereign debts have been in default for prolonged periods
before they are restructured (for example, Liberia (2009) --
more than 25 years in arrears; Iraq (2005-08) -- more than
15 years in arrears), the task is much harder.
• Greece enjoys considerable financial support from
multilateral and bilateral sources. This opens up the
possibility of being able to “credit enhance” any new Greek
debt instrument that might be issued as part of a debt
restructuring. Greece is therefore in a position similar to the
countries that issued collateralized Brady Bonds starting in
1990.
• Related to the last point, the odd nature of Greece’s
negative pledge clauses noted above (the clauses in bonds
issued prior to 2004 would not be triggered by the creation
of liens to secure future Euro-denominated indebtedness of
Greece) means that some form of collateralized Brady Bond
approach might be legally feasible for Greece without
having to obtain waivers of negative pledge restrictions in
foreign law-governed instruments issued prior to 2004.
• The fact that so few Greek bonds seem to have fallen into
the hands of retail (non-institutional) investors may also be
a blessing. Those countries (for example, Argentina (2001-
05)), that have had to deal with thousands of retail
bondholders in a debt restructuring have found this a messy
and thankless task.
• By far, however, the greatest advantage that Greece would
enjoy in a restructuring of its debt derives from the fact that
so much of the debt stock is expressly governed by Greek
law (90% or more, if our figures are correct). This raises the
6
possibility, discussed in more detail below, that the
restructuring could be facilitated in some way by a change
to Greek law.
Several other countries have restructured local lawgoverned
debts. Russia restructured Russian law-governed
instruments known as GKOs and OFZs in 1998 in parallel
with the restructuring of its English law commercial bank
debt. Uruguay restructured its local law bonds (on the
same terms as its foreign law bonds) in 2003. In each of
these prior cases, however, the local law bonds were also
denominated in local currency and formed only part of the
overall stock of the debt being restructured. While the Euro
is certainly now the local currency of Greece, it is a good
deal more besides that.
No other debtor country in modern history has been in a
position significantly to affect the outcome of a sovereign
debt restructuring by changing some feature of the law by
which the vast majority of the instruments are governed.
Disadvantages
Several features of the Greek situation may complicate any
restructuring of its debt.
• A significant percentage (perhaps more than 30 percent) of
the bonds are believed to be owned by Greek institutional
holders. A restructuring that dramatically impairs the value
of that paper could therefore place further strains on the
Greek domestic financial sector. Jamaica, which
restructured its local currency debt earlier this year, had to
walk very gingerly in designing its transaction because so
much (perhaps as much as 75%) of the affected paper was
held by Jamaican financial institutions.
• European banks are the largest holders of Greek bonds.
The stability of those institutions will be therefore very much
on the minds of Greece’s multilateral and bilateral
supporters should a debt restructuring prove unavoidable.
The sovereign debts that triggered the global debt crisis of
the 1980s were nearly all owed to international commercial
7
banks. When the debt crisis broke in 1982, the official
sector overseers of the restructuring process therefore had
to keep one eye on the debtor countries and the other on
the stability of the banking systems in the industrialized
creditor countries. It remained an uncomfortable position
for nearly seven years until the banks had time to build up
the loan loss reserves that permitted them to accept losses
in Brady Bond exchanges without alarming regulators,
stockholders or their own creditors.
In contrast, sovereign debt crises of the last 10 years or so
have affected mostly non-bank creditors -- hedge funds,
pension funds, other institutional holders of emerging
market sovereign debt, sometimes even individuals. Those
crises did not threaten the stability of the banking sectors in
creditor countries.
A restructuring of Greek debt will, in this respect, rekindle
fretful memories of the global debt crisis of the 1980s in the
minds of official sector observers.
• Greece’s debt is denominated in Euros, a currency shared
by other members of the European Union. When a Mexico
or a Philippines restructured debts denominated in U.S.
dollars in the 1980s, no one -- for that reason alone -- lost
confidence in the U.S. dollar. This same assurance cannot
be given about the restructuring of Euro-denominated debts
owed by an EU Member State.
How Might It Be Done?
Which brings us to the main event. If one were to attempt to
glean the lessons of the 50 or 60 sovereign debt restructurings of the modern
era, what would they teach about how a Greek debt restructuring should be
managed in order to achieve a prompt, orderly and fair outcome? There is
one lesson from this history that is inescapable. A sovereign debt crisis can
be a painful experience for both the debtor and its creditors; a mismanaged
sovereign debt crisis can be a catastrophically painful experience.
Transaction structure. The most likely structure for such a
transaction would be an exchange offer -- new bonds of the Hellenic
Republic would be offered in exchange for the Republic’s existing bonds.
The terms of the new bonds would determine the nature and extent of the
8
debt relief that the transaction would provide to Greece. Exchange offers
have been the norm for sovereign debt restructurings of middle income
countries since the first Brady Bond transactions in 1990.
Eligible debt. The debt eligible to participate in such an
exchange would presumably be all outstanding Greek bonds, excluding
perhaps the Treasury bills. Short-term Treasury bills have been excluded
from a number of recent sovereign debt restructurings in order to keep that
market sweet for the government’s emergency financing needs.
An interesting question will be whether some way can be found
to exclude from the restructuring the bonds in retail hands, or at least to
moderate the terms of any restructuring of those bonds. This will depend on
two things. First, the total amount of bonds in the hands of natural persons
would have to be relatively small. Institutional holders may recognize the
public relations benefit of not having widows and orphans complaining on the
evening news, but only up to a point. If the exclusion of retail holders
appreciably increases the severity of the financial sacrifice that must be
borne by institutional creditors, these sympathies will quickly fade. Second,
some mechanism must be found that will permit the government to identify
which bonds are in retail hands when the restructuring is announced.
Otherwise, bonds will tend to migrate temporarily into the hands of
individuals until the restructuring storm passes over.
New instruments. The terms of the new instrument or
instruments that would be offered in such an exchange will be a function of
the nature and extent of the debt relief the transaction is designed to
achieve. At the soft end of the spectrum would be a simple “reprofiling” of
existing bonds (or some discrete portion of them such as bonds maturing
over the next three to five years) involving a deferral of the maturity date of
each affected bond. Uruguay (2003) stretched out the maturity date of each
of its bonds by five years, while leaving the coupons untouched.
At the sharper end of the spectrum would be a transaction
designed to achieve a significant net present value (“NPV”) reduction in the
stock of debt. If Brady Bonds were chosen as the model for the transaction,
this might entail allowing holders to elect to exchange their existing credits
for either a Par Bond (a new bond exchanged at par for existing instruments,
having a long maturity and a low coupon), or a Discount Bond (a new bond
exchanged for existing instruments at a discount from the face amount of
those instruments, but typically carrying a higher coupon and perhaps a
shorter maturity than the Par Bond). The precise financial terms of the Par
9
Bond and the Discount Bond would be calibrated to achieve an equivalent
NPV reduction.
CACs. Some version of a collective action clause appears in
most of Greece’s foreign law-governed bonds. There is no reason not to use
these clauses to minimize the number of non-participating creditors.
It would work as follows: each tender of an existing bond
containing a CAC would contain a power of attorney from the owner of that
bond in favor of the government (or its exchange agent) to vote that bond at
a bondholders’ meeting (or in a written action by bondholders) in favor of a
resolution that, if approved by the requisite supermajority of holders of that
instrument, would either cause the totality of that bond to be tendered in the
exchange or cause the payment terms of the bond to be amended so as to
match the terms of one of the new instruments being offered in the
exchange. Such a resolution, if approved by the requisite supermajority of
holders (66% or 75% in Greek bonds governed by English law) would
automatically bind all holders.
Creditor consultations. As part of the restructuring process,
Greece would have to consult with significant holders of its paper, or with
committees or other ad hoc groups representing those holders. Such
consultations would be necessary to garner widespread support for the
restructuring. In addition, the IMF’s so-called “Lending Into Arrears” policy
requires a member country facing a debt restructuring to make “a good faith
effort to reach a collaborative agreement with its creditors”.
Credit enhancement. If Greece’s multilateral and bilateral
supporters were prepared to allow some portion of their emergency financing
to be used for this purpose, Greece might be able to enhance to
attractiveness of the new bonds it would offer in the exchange. In the typical
Brady Bond context, for example, the issuing countries borrowed money
from the IMF and the World Bank and used those funds to purchase U.S.
Government zero coupon obligations that were then pledged to secure the
principal payment due on the Brady Bonds at maturity. In many cases, a
pool of cash equal to 12-24 months of interest accruals on the Brady Bonds
was also set aside and pledged as partial security for the interest due on the
Brady Bonds. So the Brady Bonds represented U.S. Government risk for
principal due at maturity, and issuing country risk for interest during the life of
the Bond (apart from any amount pledged as rolling interest collateral).
The negative pledge clauses in the debt instruments of the
Brady countries did not pose an insuperable obstacle to these collateralized
10
transactions. The commercial bank creditors waived the application of the
negative pledge restrictions in their agreements, as did the World Bank and
other multilateral development banks. In the small number of cases where a
Brady country also had outstanding international bonds, arrangements were
put in place to post “equal and ratable security”.
For the reasons noted above, Greece’s negative pledge
clauses contained in bonds issued prior to 2004 would not protect holders of
those bonds in the event that Greece were to collateralize a future Eurodenominated
issue of securities. In the case of existing bonds with negative
pledge clauses that would be triggered by the issuance of a new
collateralized security, Greece would presumably seek a waiver of the
negative pledge restrictions when it invited tenders of those issues in the
exchange offer. Failing receipt of such a waiver, Greece would be obliged to
post “equal and ratable” collateral for that issue of bonds.
Credit enhancement need not take the form of collateral
security. Indeed, over time, the market grew less fond of Brady Bonds and
most countries have retired their Brady Bonds early. Obtaining a partial
guarantee of the new instruments from a creditworthy party is another option.
(The Seychelles obtained a partial guarantee from the African Development
Bank of the new debt instrument issued by the Seychelles in connection with
its debt restructuring earlier this year.) Another alternative would be to offer
holders of the new instruments a continuing “put” of those instruments to a
creditworthy party, presumably at some discount from face value. This
would allow an institutional holder of the paper to ensure that the instrument
will always have a minimum floor value, no matter what happens to the
trading price in the secondary market.
The Tactical Implications of Local Law Bonds
International investors are often leery of buying debt securities
of emerging market sovereign issuers that are governed by the law of the
issuing state. Why? Because investors fear that the sovereign might
someday be tempted to change its own law in a way that would impair the
value or the enforceability of those securities. Such changes in local law
would normally be respected by American and English courts if the debt
instruments are expressly -- or otherwise found to be -- governed by that
local law.
International capital market borrowings by industrialized
countries sometimes follow a different model. Many of these countries have
found that foreign investors are prepared to purchase local law-governed
11
debt securities of the sovereign. These investment decisions are
presumably based on a belief that industrialized countries are less likely than
some of their emerging market brethren to risk eroding future investor
confidence by opportunistically changing their own law in order to reduce
government debt service burdens.
No country in Greece’s position would lightly consider a change
of local law as an easy method of dealing with a sovereign debt crisis. The
following factors, among others, counsel extreme caution before embarking
on such a remedy.
• If done once, future investors will fear that it could be
done again. The debtor country may therefore be
compelled in future borrowings (in which international
investor participation is sought) to specify a foreign law
as the governing law of its debt instruments.
• A dramatic change in local law by one country might
allow a worm of doubt to slip into the heads of capital
market investors in other similarly-situated countries,
driving up borrowing costs around the board.
• The official sector supporters of the debtor country will
presumably balk at any action of this kind that could
unleash the forces of contagion and instability upon
other countries whose debt stocks also contain
predominantly local law-governed instruments.
• The more dramatic or confiscatory the effect of the
change of law, the higher the likelihood that it would be
subject to a successful legal challenge. More on this
below.
One legislative measure that might be perceived as balanced
and proportional in these circumstances, however, would be to enact what
amounts to a statutory collective action clause. It could operate in this way:
local law would be changed to say that if the overall exchange offer is
supported by a supermajority of affected debtholders (say, 75%, to use the
conventional CAC threshold), then the terms of any untendered local law
bonds would automatically be amended so that their payment terms (maturity
profile and interest rate) match those of one of the new instruments being
issued in the exchange.
12
Such a law, let’s call it a “Mopping-Up Law”, would thus operate
in the manner of a contractual collective action clause in a syndicated debt
instrument. Once the supermajority of creditors is persuaded to support an
amendment to the payment terms of the instrument, their decision
automatically binds any dissident minority.
Viewed another way, the Mopping-Up Law would merely
replicate at the level of the sovereign borrower the same protection enjoyed
by corporate borrowers in many countries, including Greece. For example,
we understand that in corporate reorganization proceedings under Greek
bankruptcy law, if a plan of reorganization is accepted by two thirds of the
affected creditors (including at least 40 percent of “privileged claims” such as
secured or senior claims), it will -- with court approval -- bind all creditors. A
Mopping-Up Law would achieve a similar result but at the level of a
sovereign borrower in need of a debt reorganization.
Facilitating a sovereign debt restructuring through some form of
Mopping-Up Law would be consistent with the fundamental principle that a
sovereign debtor bears the burden of persuading its creditors that a debt
restructuring is essential, that the terms of the restructuring are proportional
to the debtor’s needs, and that the sovereign is implementing economic
policies designed to restore financial health. The only question is whether
the sovereign must persuade every last debtholder of these elements, or just
a specified supermajority of affected creditors. The trend in recent years, as
evidenced by the rapidity with which CACs have been introduced into New
York-law sovereign bonds, is in favor of the supermajority threshold.
Even the relatively mild step of facilitating a debt restructuring
through the passage of a Mopping-Up Law of some kind, however, could
draw a legal challenge. In the case of Greece, such a challenge could come
from three possible sources. The first is Article 17 of the Greek Constitution.
That Article declares that no one shall be deprived of property “except for
public benefit” and conditional upon payment of full compensation
corresponding to the value of the expropriated property. The question, it
seems to us (non-Greek lawyers that we are), is whether a mandatory
alteration of the payment terms of a local law Greek bond in the context of a
generalized debt restructuring could be said to impair the value of that bond;
an instrument that, in the absence of a successful restructuring, would have
in any event been highly impaired in value. Also of possible relevance may
be Article 106 of the Greek Constitution which gives the State broad powers
to “consolidate social peace and protect the general interest.”
13
A second source of possible legal concern might lie in the
European Convention on Human Rights and its Protocols. Article 1 of
Protocol No. 1 protects the right to the “peaceful enjoyment of possessions”.
This right may be restricted only in the public interest and only through
measures that do not impose an individual and excessive burden on the
private party. That said, Article 15 of the Convention permits measures,
otherwise inconsistent with the Convention, to deal with a “public emergency
threatening the life of the nation”.
Finally, foreign holders of local law-governed Greek bonds
subject to the Mopping-Up Law might look to Greece’s Bilateral Investment
Treaties for redress. BITs protect against expropriation without
compensation, as well as unfair and inequitable treatment. It appears that
Greece has signed more than 40 BITs with bilateral partners.
Assuming some version of a Mopping-Up Law could survive
any legal challenge, however, it could have significant tactical implications for
a Greek debt restructuring. More than 90% of Greek bonds are governed by
local law. If, to use our example, holders of 75% of all eligible bonds (local
law and foreign law) were to support a restructuring, our version of a
Mopping-Up Law should operate to ensure that more than 90% of the debt
stock will be covered by the restructuring. The Mopping-Up Law would not
affect holders of foreign law bonds. Participation by those holders would
need to be encouraged by moral suasion and the use of contractual
collective action clauses in the relevant bonds.
How Long Would a Restructuring Take?
Our guess? If done efficiently, five to six months, less if
necessary.
One month or so would be needed for preparation; one to two
months for creditor consultations; one month during which the exchange
offer would be in the market and road shows would take place; another four
to six weeks to convene bondholder meetings for those bonds containing
CACs, and two to four weeks to prepare for a closing.
If done efficiently.
* * * *
Σενάρια αναδιάρθρωσης μέχρι εξόδου από το ευρώ.
ΑΜΕΡΙΚΑΝΟΙ ΣΥΜΒΟΥΛΟΙ ΤΗΣ ΚΥΒΕΡΝΗΣΗΣ ΣΕ ΑΝΑΖΗΤΗΣΗ ΡΙΖΙΚΩΝ ΛΥΣΕΩΝ
Σενάρια αναδιάρθρωσης μέχρι εξόδου από το ευρώ
Της ΜΑΤΙΝΑΣ ΣΤΕΒΗ
Με απ' ευθείας ανάθεση και χωρίς πολλές λεπτομέρειες, η Ελλάδα απασχολεί κορυφαία αμερικανική δικηγορική εταιρεία, η οποία εδώ και ένα χρόνο εξετάζει τον τρόπο ολοκληρωτικής αναδιάρθρωσης του χρέους και τη δυνατότητα εξόδου της χώρας από την ευρωζώνη.
Στις 27 Ιουλίου η ελληνική κυβέρνηση ανακοίνωσε την ανάθεση του ρόλου χρηματοοικονομικών συμβούλων για το εν εξελίξει πρόγραμμα ανταλλαγής ομολόγων στις τράπεζες ΒΝΡ Paribas, Deutsche Bank και HSBC. Στην ίδια ανακοίνωση αναφέρεται η συνεργασία της κυβέρνησης με τη νεοϋορκέζικη δικηγορική εταιρεία Cleary Gottlieb (πλήρες όνομα «Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen and Hamilton LLP») «ως διεθνούς νομικού συμβούλου (...) σε σχέση με την εφαρμογή του PSI». Οπως είναι σε θέση να γνωρίζει η «Ε», όμως, η πρόσληψη της εν λόγω εταιρείας κάθε άλλο παρά απλή υπόθεση είναι.
Ποια είναι η Cleary Gottlieb
Πρόκειται για μία από τις μεγαλύτερες και ισχυρότερες δικηγορικές εταιρείες της Νέας Υόρκης, με εξειδίκευση σε τραπεζικές και χρηματοοικονομικές υποθέσεις. Η εταιρεία εδραιώθηκε μέσω της ανάμειξής της στις αναδιαρθρώσεις χρέους της Ουρουγουάης, της Αργεντινής και, πιο πρόσφατα, της Ισλανδίας.
Επικεφαλής της ομάδας που θα δουλέψει στην Ελλάδα και «αστέρας» της εταιρείας σε ζητήματα αναδιάρθρωσης χρέους είναι ο δικηγόρος Λι Μπούχαϊτ, ο οποίος εκπροσώπησε τις κυβερνήσεις της Ισλανδίας και της Αργεντινής κατά τις διαπραγματεύσεις τους με τους πιστωτές τους.
Ο κ. Μπούχαϊτ είχε αρχίσει να ασχολείται με το ελληνικό θέμα πολύ πριν η εταιρεία του προσληφθεί από τη χώρα μας. Συγκεκριμένα εξέδωσε, σε συνεργασία με τον καθηγητή Δικαίου του Πανεπιστημίου Ντιουκ των ΗΠΑ, Μίτου Γκουλάτι, δύο μελέτες. Η πρώτη, τον Απρίλιο του 2010, είχε τίτλο «Πώς να αναδιαρθρώσουμε το ελληνικό χρέος», ενώ η δεύτερη, του Απριλίου 2011, «Ελληνικό χρέος: Τα τελικά σενάρια».
Και οι δύο μελέτες, οι οποίες είναι ελεύθερα διαθέσιμες στο Διαδίκτυο, εξετάζουν εις βάθος το νομικό καθεστώς των ελληνικών ομολόγων και τις εναλλακτικές που έχει στη διάθεσή της η Ελλάδα, μεταξύ των οποίων και η ολική αναδιάρθρωση του χρέους.
Η συνάντηση της Ρώμης
Αυτό που δεν έχει γίνει ώς τώρα γνωστό, όμως, είναι το γεγονός ότι η Cleary Gottlieb οργάνωσε συνέδριο κεκλεισμένων των θυρών στη Ρώμη στις 3 Φεβρουαρίου, με συμμετοχή του κ. Μπούχαϊτ και υψηλόβαθμων στελεχών από άλλες διεθνείς δικηγορικές εταιρείες, με αντικείμενο την αναδιάρθρωση του ελληνικού χρέους και το ενδεχόμενο εξόδου από την ευρωζώνη.
Συγκεκριμένα, εισήγηση που παρουσιάστηκε και συζητήθηκε εκεί, την οποία έχει στη διάθεσή της η «Ε», εξετάζει την εθελοντική έξοδο ή έξωση χώρας από την ευρωζώνη και πώς αυτή μπορεί να γίνει σύννομα, παρά την έλλειψη σχετικής πρόβλεψης στις συνθήκες του Μάαστριχτ και της Λισαβόνας.
Η συγκεκριμένη εισήγηση παρουσιάστηκε από τον δικηγόρο Τσαρλς Πρόκτορ, της λονδρέζικης εταιρείας Μπερντ & Μπερντ, με τίτλο «Φεύγοντας από την ευρωζώνη» και αποτέλεσε αντικείμενο συζήτησης μετά την παρουσίασή της ανάμεσα στον κ. Πρόκτορ, τον κ. Μπούχαϊτ και τους λοιπούς συνέδρους της Cleary Gottlieb.
Στην παρουσίαση αναγνωρίζεται η νομική δυσκολία εξόδου από την ευρωζώνη, λόγω των διατάξεων των συνθηκών του Μάαστριχτ και της Λισαβόνας, παρουσιάζεται όμως ένα «παράθυρο» για εθελοντική και μόνο αποχώρηση. Συγκεκριμένα, το άρθρο 50 της συνθήκης του Μάαστριχτ, το οποίο αποτελεί μεταγενέστερη προσθήκη που έγινε στη Λισαβόνα, επιτρέπει σε χώρα να αποχωρήσει από την Ευρωπαϊκή Ενωση «ανάλογα με τις συνταγματικές διατάξεις του κράτους-μέλους».
Σύμφωνα με την ανάλυση που παρουσιάστηκε στο συνέδριο της Cleary Gottlieb, εάν μία χώρα επιθυμεί να αποχωρήσει από την ευρωζώνη πρέπει πρώτα να κάνει χρήση του συγκεκριμένου άρθρου και να αποχωρήσει από την Ε.Ε. «Συνεπώς, υπάρχει μηχανισμός εξόδου που περιλαμβάνει την Ε.Ε. και την ευρωζώνη», επισημαίνεται στην εισήγηση, ενώ «δεν υφίσταται διαδικασία υπό την οποία κράτος-μέλος να μπορεί να αποχωρήσει από την ευρωζώνη αλλά να παραμείνει στην Ε.Ε.».
Τέλος, στην εισήγηση σημειώνεται ότι ενδεχομένως υπό άλλο άρθρο της συνθήκης του Μάαστριχτ το απερχόμενο κράτος να μπορεί άμεσα να κάνει αίτηση για να ξαναμπεί στην Ε.Ε. έχοντας αποχωρήσει από την ευρωζώνη.
Σε κανένα σημείο της εισήγησης δεν γίνεται αναφορά στην Ελλάδα συγκεκριμένα, ενδεχομένως για προσχηματικούς λόγους, καθότι το αντικείμενο της συνεδρίασης ήταν ούτως ή άλλως η Ελλάδα.
Παρά τη μυστικότητα της συνάντησης, η ιταλική οικονομική εφημερίδα «Linkiesta» με άρθρο της στις 10 Φεβρουαρίου έγραφε ότι «η Ελλάδα μπορεί να σπάσει το ταμπού και να βγει από την ευρωζώνη. Μεγάλες δικηγορικές εταιρείες απεργάζονται σχέδια ώστε αυτό να γίνει με νόμιμο τρόπο, χωρίς να παραβιάζονται οι κανόνες της Ευρωπαϊκής Ενωσης».
Σε άρθρο των «Financial Times» την 1η Αυγούστου, η εφημερίδα σχολίαζε την πρόσληψη της Cleary Gottlieb από την Ελλάδα και ειδικά τον ρόλο του κ. Μπούχαϊτ. Η πρόσληψη ερμηνευόταν ως επιθετική κίνηση από την πλευρά της ελληνικής κυβέρνησης, δεδομένου του ιστορικού του κ. Μπούχαϊτ ως σκληρού διαπραγματευτή σε παλαιότερες αναδιαρθρώσεις αλλά κυρίως λόγω των απόψεών του για το ενδεχόμενο ελληνικής αναδιάρθρωσης εκτός συμφωνιών με την Ε.Ε.
Συγκεκριμένα, αφού παρουσίαζε τη θέση του κ. Μπούχαϊτ για ολική αναδιάρθρωση του ελληνικού χρέους που διοικείται από ελληνικό δίκαιο με τρόπο ιδιαίτερα επώδυνο για τους ξένους πιστωτές, ο δημοσιογράφος της έγκριτης οικονομικής εφημερίδας σημείωνε καυστικά: «Σας ακούγονται όλα αυτά σαν μονομερής και αντι-ευρωπαϊκή δράση; Ισως, όμως φαίνεται ότι οι λέξεις "πολυμερής", "ευρωπαϊκή" και "δράση" δεν συνδυάζονται με επιτυχία αυτές τις μέρες».
Τα ερωτήματα
Σε επικοινωνία που είχαμε με την Cleary Gottlieb μάς επιβεβαιώθηκε η πρόσληψή της από την ελληνική κυβέρνηση για το πρόγραμμα ανταλλαγής ομολόγων, στο πλαίσιο των αποφάσεων της συνόδου κορυφής της 21ης Ιουλίου. Η εταιρεία δεν ήταν σε θέση να μας εξηγήσει πώς έγινε η συνεργασία (με απ' ευθείας ανάθεση, κατόπιν πρωτοβουλίας ποίου;) ούτε αν ο ρόλος της περιορίζεται στο πρόγραμμα ανταλλαγής ομολόγων.
Επίσης, παρ' ότι μας επιβεβαίωσε την πραγματοποίηση του συνεδρίου της Ρώμης, η Cleary Gottlieb δεν ήταν σε θέση να μας δώσει λεπτομέρειες για τον λόγο και την αφορμή της διοργάνωσής του.
Τα ερωτήματα λοιπόν παραμένουν: Πώς επιλέχθηκε η Cleary Gottlieb; Θα παίξει ευρύτερο ρόλο νομικού συμβούλου της Ελλάδας; Ποια η άποψη της κυβέρνησης για το έντονο ενδιαφέρον της εταιρείας για το πώς μπορεί να γίνει ολική αναδιάρθρωση του χρέους και το ενδεχόμενο εξόδου από την ευρωζώνη; Είναι και αυτά σενάρια που εξετάζονται;
Εγγραφή σε:
Αναρτήσεις (Atom)